EIRP Proceedings, Vol 10 (2015)

The Stackelberg Model for a Leader

of Production and Many Satellites



Catalin Angelo Ioan1, Gina Ioan2



Abstract: Oligopoly is a market situation where there are a small number of bidders (at least two) of a good non-substituent and a sufficient number of consumers. The paper analyses the Stackelberg model for a leader of production and many satellites. There are obtained the equilibrium productions, maximum profits and sales price where one of the company is the leader of quantity, and other satellites. There are also survey the situations where the firm based on its marginal cost of production can effectively take the lead of production.

Keywords: oligopoly; Stackelberg; equilibrium

JEL Classification: D43



1 Introduction

Oligopoly is a market situation where there are a small number of bidders (at least two) of a good non-substituent and a sufficient number of consumers. Oligopoly composed of two producers called duopoly.

Considering any number of competing firms producing the same normal good, is interesting the analysis of each activity in response to the activity of other companies.

Each of them when it sets the production and the sale price will be considered the productions and prices of other firms. If one of the companies will settle the price or the quantity produced, the other adjusting after it, then the price will be called leader of price or leader of production, the others called price satellites or production satellites.



2 The Stackelberg Model for a Leader of Production and Many Satellites

Consider now m firms Fi, i= , a function of price: p(Q)=a-bQ, a,b0 and the total cost of production TCi=iQ, i= , where i is the marginal cost of firm Fi.

Consider now that the company Fs is a leader of production, where s= is fixed. It sets at a given time a production Qs.

Considering a certain satellite Fk, it will establish a production that will seek to maximize its profit but at the same time it will take into account the production of the leader which will influence the selling price of the product. Therefore, let the firm Fk, k= , ks reaction function:

Qk= , i= , is

The leader’s profit Fs is through price, a function of both its production and those of satellites:

=

Taking into account the reaction functions of satellites: Qi= , i= , is follows:

=

The profit of a satellite Fk, ks is:

= , ks

The condition of profit maximization of the leader Fs is:

=

and for satellite Fk:

= =0, k= , ks

In conditions that the production of the company Fs is given, we have the system of equations:

, k= , ks

Adding the resulting m-1 relationships: from where: .

Substituting in the above formula, we find that:

- the reaction function of Fk to Fs, k= , ks

Substituting in the condition of profit maximization of the leader, follows:

the satellite production of Fk being:

, k= , ks

But now, the condition that Fs be really production leader returns to: , k= , ks that is:

, k= , ks

which finally leads to:

Therefore, the marginal cost of Fs will be higher limited to:

sups=

If ic - constant, i= , is resulting from the above: .

Following these considerations, in order that the company Fs to maintain or to assume leadership role it is necessary that its marginal cost is higher limited by sups.

The maximum profits of the firms will be:

= =

= = , k= , ks
The condition that the profit leader be higher than that of any satellite returns to:

from where:

Therefore, the marginal cost of the leader must satisfy the condition imposed by the upper limit sups and the expression above, otherwise the company is not leading amount or if in affirmative case doesn’t have a higher maximum profit than the one of the satellites.

For two companies Fs and Fk (m=2) the condition that the maximum profit of the leader be higher than that of the satellite becomes:

The requirement that is equivalent with .
Therefore, if:
we have: and if: follows that: .

Returning to the case of the m firms the selling price is:

p*= = 0

From here, it follows:

p*=

Therefore, a change in the marginal cost of the leader with an amount , will lead to a change in price and a change of all others will change by an amount .

Returning to the situation of the two companies Fs and Fk, the condition that Fs be leader was:

It is possible that none of the companies can not be a leader? It should, in this case that and that is:

Considering the straight lines: and we get the situation in Figure 1:

Figure 1.

Therefore, when a firm's marginal cost is sufficiently large relative to the other, it can not take the lead. If the two firms have marginal costs comparable to each other, but large enough, none can assume leadership, the reverse situation being when the marginal costs are low enough, the two companies being able to assume each leadership role.



3 References

Ioan, C.A. & Ioan, G. (2012), Matheconomics. Galati: Zigotto.

Ioan, C.A. & Ioan, G. (2012). General Considerations on the Oligopoly. Acta Universitatis Danubius. Oeconomica, Vol. 8, No. 3, pp. 115-137.

Spence, M. (1984). Cost reduction, competition, and industry performance. Econometrica,Vol. 52, No.1, pp. 101-121.

Van Damme, E. & S. Hurkens (1999). Endogenous Stackelberg leadership. Games and Economic Behavior, Vol. 28, No.1, pp. 105-129.



1 Associate Professor, PhD, “Danubius” University of Galati, Romania, Address: 3 Galati Boulevard, 800654 Galati, Romania, Tel.: +40.372.361.102, fax: +40.372.361.290, Corresponding author: catalin_angelo_ioan@univ-danubius.ro.

2 Assistant professor, PhD, “Danubius” University of Galati, Romania, Address: 3 Galati Boulevard, 800654 Galati, Romania, Tel.: +40.372.361.102, fax: +40.372.361.290, E-mail: ginaioan@univ-danubius.ro.

Refbacks

  • There are currently no refbacks.
Creative Commons License
This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.